A new study looks at the long-run evolution of rent sharing between companies and workers in the UK and finds that rent sharing has significantly decreased between 2001 and 2016, particularly among companies that enjoy monopolistic markups.

 

 

Stagnating real wages and falling labor shares across developed economies have stimulated a renewed interest in the question of how, and to what extent, rents are shared with labor. Nicholas Kaldor’s (1957) long-held stylized fact that the fraction of national income going to labour is fixed has been questioned, for instance, by Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014), who show that the global labor share has dropped from 65 percent in 1980 to 59 percent today. Over the same period, US labor productivity has grown by 90 percent but the median real wage only by a paltry 10 percent, rekindling debates about whether growth benefits workers which date from as far back as Ricardo to the highly influential contemporary work of Thomas Piketty.

 

In response to these developments, scholars have again turned their attention to firms and their wage-setting process. David Autor, John Van Reenen and co-authors (2017), building on the seminal works of Michał Kalecki (1938), have recently reconnected the distribution of income with the behavior of firms and their market power. The question is: How does the power structure in product and labor markets translate into wage stagnation and a lower labor share? A classic account says that workers lose bargaining power, and therefore they are less able to claim a portion of a firm’s rents, a phenomena known as rent sharing. Knowing how rent sharing has evolved over time can therefore help understand changes in the position of workers within companies and shed light on the mechanisms behind the fall in the labour share. However—and at least, in part, owing to a lack of data—the reality is that little is known about long-run changes in rent sharing.

 

Our recent paper (Bell et al. 2018) aims to redress this by looking at the long-run evolution of rent sharing among UK-domiciled companies. It features the compilation of a comprehensive and consistent panel of the top 300 companies (by market capitalization) listed on the London Stock Exchange from 1983 until 2016. The sample includes well-known British companies such as BP, British American Tobacco, Tesco and G4S, which have played an important role in the British economy throughout the last few decades. It also covers all sectors of the economy, which is crucial given the dramatic shift from manufacturing to services occurring in the UK since the 1980s. 

 

The prime empirical focus of the paper is to examine rent sharing, and its temporal variation, by estimating the elasticity of firm-level average wages with respect to firm’s profits per employee, after accounting for all time-invariant firm characteristics and outside-firm forces shaping wages (e.g. the unemployment rate, industry-level wages, and other common effects over time). We deal with the potential endogeneity—that the profit-pay link may work in both directions—by instrumenting firm-level profits with their lags or industry-average profits.

 

The first result to emerge is of a positive and statistically significant rent-sharing parameter. Estimating over the whole sample, this rent sharing elasticity is fairly modest in magnitude. A one percent increase in profits implies around 0.01 percent increase in wages. The second, more novel result concerns the time series evolution of rent sharing: There is a substantial fall in the long-run elasticity from 0.043 in the period 1983-2000 to 0.012 in the period 2001-2016.

 

The finding of a significantly reduced rent sharing parameter proves robust to various specification checks and alternative definitions of the sample. Moreover, the same result emerges for a panel of UK manufacturing companies, which provides data on domestic operations only. In addition, industry-level data for the US and for nine EU countries again show the same pattern. Consistent with the firm analysis, there is a strongly falling rent sharing for almost all countries since the early 2000s (EU) and the 1970-80s (US).

 

The elasticities might appear small, but one should keep in mind that profits can be extremely volatile, so even a small elasticity might have significant implication for wages. To illustrate this, Figure 1 shows the so-called Lester range, which is a rent sharing-induced wage gap between firms from the bottom and the top of the distribution of profits per employee (distance of four standard deviations). For instance, in our main sample (Top 300, black solid line), between 1983-1991 very profitable companies paid on average 50 percent higher wages only because of rent sharing, compared to non-profitable companies. After 2009, the gap has narrowed to merely 10 percent, implying that companies shared profits with workers to a much lesser extent.

 

Figure 1: The rent-sharing-induced wage gap between firms from the bottom and the top of the distribution of profits per employee (distance of four standard deviations)

 

As mentioned before, the recent literature has shown that the aggregate fall in the labor share is driven by companies with high market power (Autor et al. 2017). It is therefore natural to ask whether these companies are also responsible for the fall in rent sharing. Figure 2 shows the estimates of rent sharing elasticity to be conditional on the percentile of firm’s market power (measured by market share). On average, companies with higher market power share more of their rents than companies with low power. However, the positive association between market power and rent sharing is significantly weaker in the period 2001-2016 compared to 1983-2001. In other words, the fall in rent sharing was more pronounced among the companies which enjoy monopolistic markups.

 

Figure 2: Estimates of rent-sharing elasticity conditional on the percentile of firm’s market power (measured by market share)

 

These findings have implications for debates regarding the future of work. A decline in rent sharing implies growing income inequalities (especially between labor and capital) and may encourage calls for a bigger role for redistributive policies. It also suggests a fundamental change in the competitiveness of the labor market. A weaker bargaining position for workers might be a result of technological change (“robocalypse”), higher labor mobility and institutional change (e.g. decline of unions). Finally, companies with higher market power experience relatively larger falls in rent sharing, suggesting that competition policies should also be analyzed from the labor market perspective. As these companies are increasingly global, with many have value chains connected across countries, one might expect these trends to become world-wide phenomena.

 

Brian Bell is a senior lecturer in economics at King’s College London and associate at the LSE’s Centre for Economic Performance (CEP). Pawel Bukowski is a research economist at CEP. Stephen Machin is professor of economics at LSE and director of CEP. This blog post is based on the authors’ Rent Sharing and Inclusive Growth, discussion paper 1584, Centre for Economic Performance (CEP).

 

References

 

Autor, D., Dorn, D., Katz, L. F., Patterson, C., & Van Reenen, J. (2017). The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms. CEP DP 1482. Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.

 

Bell, B., Bukowski, P., & Machin, S. (2018). Rent Sharing and Inclusive Growth. CEP DP 1584. Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.

 

Kaldor, N. (1957). A model of economic growth. The Economic Journal, 67(268), 591-624.

 

Kalecki, M. (1938). The Determinants of Distribution of the National Income. Econometrica, 6(2), 97-112.

 

Karabarbounis, L., & Neiman, B. (2013). The global decline of the labor share. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1), 61-103.

 

Disclaimer: The ProMarket blog is dedicated to discussing how competition tends to be subverted by special interests. The posts represent the opinions of their writers, not necessarily those of the University of Chicago, the Booth School of Business, or its faculty. For more information, please visit ProMarket Blog Policy