Democracy sees higher GDP due to greater civil liberties, economic reform, increased investment and government capacity, and reduced social conflict.

(Note: this post originally appeared in VoxDev.org)

Many analysts view democracy as a neutral or negative factor for growth. In this column, we discuss new evidence showing that democracy has a robust and sizable pro-growth effect. The central estimates suggest that a country that switches from non-democracy to democracy achieves about 20 percent higher GDP per capita over the subsequent three decades.

A belief that democracy is bad for economic growth is common in both academic political economy as well as the popular press. Robert Barro’s seminal research in this area concluded that “[m]ore political rights do not have an effect on growth…The first lesson is that democracy is not the key to economic growth” (Barro 1997: 1 and 11). Meanwhile, reacting to the rise of China, New York Times columnist Tom Friedman argues:

“One-party non-democracy certainly has its drawbacks. But when it is led by a reasonably enlightened group of people, as China is today, it can also have great advantages. That one party can just impose the politically difficult but critically important policies needed to move a society forward in the 21st century […]”

The study

In Acemoglu et al. (2014), we present evidence from a panel of countries between 1960 and 2010 challenging this view. Our results show a robust and sizable effect of democracy on economic growth. Our central estimates suggest that a country that switches from non-democracy to democracy achieves about 20 percent higher GDP per capita in the long run (over roughly the next 30 years). These are large but not implausible effects, and suggest that the global rise in democracy over the past 50 years (of over 30 percentage points) has yielded roughly 6 percent higher world GDP.

Challenges in estimating impact

There are several challenges in estimating the impact of democracy on growth:

  • Existing democracy indices are typically subject to considerable measurement error, leading to spurious changes in the democracy score of a country even if its democratic institutions do not truly change.

  • As shown in Figure 1, democratizations are preceded by a temporary fall in GDP. A reliable estimate of the impact of democracy on future GDP therefore needs to model and estimate the dynamics of the GDP process.

  • Even with year and country fixed effects, changes in democracy may be correlated with other changes or respond to current or future economic conditions, raising obvious omitted variable bias concerns (Acemoglu et al. 2005, Brückner and Ciccone 2011).

Figure 1

The analysis

Datasets

We deal with all these challenges in our study. We build on the important work by Papaioannou and Siourounis (2008) to develop a dichotomous index of democracy, purged of spurious changes in democracy scores available in the standard datasets, and rely on this measure for most of our analysis. We use information from both the Freedom House and Polity data sets, as well as other codings of democracies, to resolve ambiguous cases. This leads to a 0-1 measure of democracy for 184 countries annually from 1960 (or post-1960 year of independence) to 2010.

Estimating explicit dynamics

Importantly, we allow for and estimate explicit dynamics of (log) GDP using a number of different strategies. Given the pattern in Figure 1, our first strategy is to control for lags of GDP in linear regressions, including a full set of country and year fixed effects. To overcome any possible Nickell bias, owing to lagged dependent variables, we show our results hold with generalized method of moments (GMM) estimators, as proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991), and Hahn et al. (2001).

Our second strategy is to adapt to our panel context propensity-score-based matching estimators, proposed in Angrist and Kuersteiner (2012) and Angrist et al. (2013), to correct for the effects of GDP dynamics. The propensity score reweighted data can be seen in Figure 2.

Figure 2

Probability of democratizing

We predict the probability of democratizing based on four years of GDP, and then reweight country-years. This means we are effectively comparing the path of GDP following a democratization, with the path of GDP following an ‘almost democratization’ (those countries that look likely to have a transition based on the trajectory of prior GDP).

As Figure 2 shows, there is no difference in the years prior to the democratization (even those years not used to predict the propensity score). However, the large difference in GDP in the subsequent years shows that the increase in GDP in Figure 1 is not merely an artifact of the dynamics of GDP in the years preceding a political transition.

Regional democratization

Finally, in addition to controlling for country and year fixed effects, we use an instrumental variables (IV) strategy to overcome omitted variable bias. Inspired by Samuel Huntington’s work documenting waves of democracy, we develop an instrument for democracy based on regional waves of democratization (Persson and Tabellini 2008 develop a similar instrument for ‘democratic capital’).

Our identification assumption is that democratization in a country spreads to other nondemocratic countries in the same region, but does not have a direct differential impact on economic growth in these countries (at least conditional on lagged levels of country and regional GDP, and various covariates that could be correlated with country-level GDP at the year, region, and initial regime level). These IV estimates yield long-run effects quite close to our main estimates.

Control: GDP lags

We also re-estimate our results using a variety of other democracy measures used in the literature. We find that when dynamics are not accounted for, the signs and significance of the coefficients vary widely. However, when lags of GDP are included as controls, all the other democracy measures yield positive coefficients. In addition, the IV coefficients are much larger than the OLS coefficients compared to our measure, suggesting that we have reduced the measurement error in the democracy variable.

Discussion: Democracy in low-income countries

What is the common view that democracy isn’t suitable for low-income countries founded on? The pages of The New York Times are again a good guide to public opinion, this time in the words of David Brooks, defending the Egyptian military coup:

“It’s not that Egypt doesn’t have a recipe for a democratic transition. It seems to lack even the basic mental ingredients.”

Judge Posner also agrees with this conclusion and writes:

“Dictatorship will often be optimal for very poor countries. Such countries tend not only to have simple economies but also to lack the cultural and institutional preconditions to democracy.”

Is there any evidence that democracy is only good for already developed economies? The answer is no. Though we do find that democratizations are associated with larger increases in GDP per capita in countries with higher levels of secondary schooling, there is no evidence that democracy is bad for economic growth in low income economies or even in economies with low levels of schooling.

Why does democracy increase growth?

Our strategy is not well suited to disentangling particular growth mechanisms, but we attempt to disaggregate both the dimensions of democracy and proximate determinants of growth. When we disentangle what components of democracy matter the most for growth, we find that civil liberties are what seem to be the most important. We also find positive effects of democracy on economic reforms, private investment, the size and capacity of government, and a reduction in social conflict.

Clearly all of these are channels by which democracy can increase economic growth, and a great deal of further research is needed. Together with our previous work showing that democracy had no effect on inequality, these results suggest the interaction between democratic institutions and the level and distribution of income is more complex than the previous literature suggests.

(Editor’s note: A previous version of this column can be found on VoxEU.)

References

Acemoglu, D (2008), “Oligarchic Vs. Democratic Societies”, Journal of the European Economic Association 6(1): 1–44.

Acemoglu, D, Johnson, S, Robinson, J A and Yared, P (2008), “Income and Democracy”, American Economic Review 98(3): 808–842.

Acemoglu, D, Naidu, S, Restrepo, P and Robinson, J A (2013), “Democracy, Redistribution and Inequality”, NBER Working Paper No. 19746.

Acemoglu, D, Naidu, S, Restrepo, P and Robinson, J A (2014), “Democracy Does Cause Growth”, the NBER Working Paper No. 20004.

Angrist, J D and Kuersteiner, G M (2011), “Causal Effects of Monetary Shocks: Semi- parametric Conditional Independence Tests with a Multinomial Propensity Score”, Review of Economics and Statistics 93(3): 725–747.

Angrist, J D, Jord`a, O and Kuersteiner, G (2013), “Semiparametric Estimates of Monetary Policy Effects: String Theory Revisited”, NBER Working Paper No. 19355.

Arellano, M and Bond, S (1991), “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations”, Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277–297.

Barro, R J (1997), Getting it Right: Markets and Choices in a Free Society, MIT Press.

Bruckner, M and Ciccone, A (2011), “Rain and the Democratic Window of Opportunity”, Econometrica 79(3): 923–947.

Hahn, J, Hausman, J A and Kuersteiner, G (2001), “Bias Corrected Instrumental Variables Estimation for Dynamic Panel Models with Fixed Effects”, MIT Department of Economics, Working Paper No. 01-24.

Huntington, S P (1991), The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century, University of Oklahoma Press.

Papaioannou, E and Siourounis, G (2008), “Democratisation and Growth”, Economic Journal 118(532): 1520-1551.

Persson, T and Tabellini, G (2009), “Democratic Capital: The Nexus of Political and Economic Change”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1(2): 88–126.

Disclaimer: The ProMarket blog is dedicated to discussing how competition tends to be subverted by special interests. The posts represent the opinions of their writers, not those of the University of Chicago, the Booth School of Business, or its faculty. For more information, please visit ProMarket Blog Policy.